Growing up in Paris, Vincent Rollet was exposed to the world beyond France from an early age. His dad was an engineer who traveled around the globe to set up electrical infrastructure, and he moved the family to the United States for two years when Rollet was a small child. His father’s work sparked Rollet’s interest in international development and growth. “It made me want to see and learn how things work in other parts of the world,” he says.
Today, Rollet is a fifth-year PhD student in MIT’s Department of Economics, studying how cities evolve — and how they may become constrained by their past. “Cities constantly need to adapt to economic changes,” he explains. “For example, you might need more housing as populations grow, or want to transform manufacturing spaces into modern lab facilities. With the rise of remote work, many cities now have excess office space that could potentially become residential housing.” Ultimately, Rollet hopes his research can influence urban policymakers to better serve city residents.
A happy accident
Rollet’s first exposure to economics was almost accidental. As a teenager, he stumbled upon the lecture videos of a game theory course at Yale University. “I randomly clicked on the available courses,” he said, “and I watched the videos, and I found it interesting.”
In high school and college, he focused on math and physics. “It’s the kind of training you’re typically pushed to do in France,” he says. But at the end of his first year at École Polytechnique — mandatory military training for all students — he remembered the Yale course that he had watched in high school. He had spent that year helping run a military service program for disadvantaged youth. “I was looking for an enjoyable way to start studying again,” he says. “So I went back to game theory.”
Rollet decided to take a game theory course with an economics professor, Pierre Boyer, who would play a key role in his academic path. Through conversations with Boyer, Rollet learned that economics could provide a rigorous, mathematical approach to understanding the topics around international development and international politics that had long fascinated him. Boyer introduced Rollet to two MIT-trained economists, professors Vincent Pons and Benjamin Marx, with whom he continues to collaborate today. A research visit to the U.S. in 2019 to work with them solidified his interest in pursuing graduate school. Shortly thereafter, he began his PhD at MIT.
Why cities get “stuck”
Rollet’s research explores why cities struggle to adapt their built environments as economic conditions shift, and why certain urban spaces become “stuck” in outdated patterns of development. He’s drawn to cities because they are a microcosm of different interacting systems in economics. “To understand cities, you need to understand how labor markets work, how the housing market works, and how transportation works,” he notes.
Rollet has spent most of his PhD focusing on New York City. By examining detailed data on building permits, real estate transactions, rents, and zoning changes, he has tracked the evolution of every building in the city over nearly two decades, studying when and why developers choose to demolish buildings and construct new ones, and how these decisions are influenced by economic, regulatory, and technological constraints. By combining computational theory and data — which often includes information on natural experiments (i.e., What happens when a city changes a regulation?) — Rollet aims to reveal generalizable principles underlying how cities grow and evolve.
Originally shaped as a manufacturing hub with dense commercial centers and sprawling residential outskirts, New York’s physical structure has been largely frozen since zoning regulations were imposed in the 1960s. Despite dramatic shifts in population and economic activity, the city’s regulations have barely budged, creating profound mismatches: soaring housing costs, overcrowded residential areas, and underutilized commercial spaces. The buildings are expensive to replace, and regulations are notoriously hard to change once they are established.
Rollet’s findings reveal critical inefficiencies. In cities like New York or Boston, housing often sells for hundreds of thousands of dollars more than it costs to build. This large gap suggests that demand far outpaces supply: There simply aren’t enough homes being built. “When the housing supply is too constrained, we are effectively wasting resources, making housing unnecessarily expensive,” he explains.
But implementing any kind of action or policy to alleviate these inefficiencies has downstream effects. For example, it can have different impacts on different groups of people. “There will be winners and losers,” Rollet explains. “One reason is that you might directly care about the welfare of a certain group, like directly providing housing for lower-income households. Another reason is that if there are sufficiently many people who are losers of a certain policy, or if they’re sufficiently powerful, they’re going to be able to block the policy change, and this poses a political constraint.”
So what makes a city “stuck”? “Much of the time,” Rollet says, “it’s policy.” But the effects of policy changes take time to materialize and might be difficult for people to detect. Rollet cites Cambridge’s recent zoning reform allowing the construction of six-story buildings as a case in point. “These policy changes can benefit a lot of people, by reducing the housing prices a bit for everyone,” he says, “but individual people won’t know it. This makes collective action very hard.”
Economics, however, provides a toolkit to characterize and quantify these effects. “What economists can bring to the table is to give policymakers more information on the likely consequences of their policy actions,” Rollet says.
Striving to “improve things”
As Rollet enters the home stretch of his PhD, he’s grateful to his advisors in the economics department for helping him develop a foundation for the diverse set of tools necessary for his work. From professors Dave Donaldson and David Atkin, he learned how to adapt methods traditionally used in the study of international trade, to analyze the movement of people across neighborhoods and cities. From Professor Tobias Salz, he gained insights into modeling the behavior of firms over time, which he now applies to understanding the actions of real estate developers. “The training here pushes you to produce research that truly stands out,“ he says. “The courses helped me discover a new set of fields and methods.”
Beyond research, Rollet actively contributes to his department, including serving as the co-president of the Graduate Economics Association. “MIT is truly the best place for economics, not just because of their courses, but because it’s a really friendly department where people help each other out,” he says. “The Graduate Economics Association helps to build that sense of community, and I wanted to be a part of that.” In addition, he is a member of a mental health and peer support group in the department.
Rollet also enjoys teaching. He has been a teaching assistant for microeconomics and international trade courses and has built an impressive writing repertoire explaining complex concepts in several fields. In high school, one of Rollet’s hobbies was writing quantum theory explainers on the internet for general audiences. Some publishers found his writing and contacted him about turning it into a book. The book was published, and has sold more than 14,000 copies. As a college student, Rollet worked on two books: one on game theory for general audiences, and an intro to economics textbook that two professors recruited him to co-author. It’s still the standard textbook at École Polytechnique today. “It was my Covid activity,” Rollet laughs.
Looking forward, Rollet aims to pursue a career in research and teaching. His immediate goal remains clear: develop research that meaningfully impacts policy, by shedding light on how cities can overcome constraints and evolve in ways that better serve their residents. He’s excited about how, in the future, more fine-grained and detailed data sources could shed light on how micro behavior can lead to macro outcomes.
"Housing and cities — these markets are failing in important ways in many parts of the world. There’s real potential for policy to improve things.”